class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide # Lesson 5: The Macroeconomics of Development ## ECON 317 · Economics of Development · Fall 2019 ### Ryan Safner
Assistant Professor of Economics
safner@hood.edu
ryansafner/devf19
devF19.classes.ryansafner.com
--- class: inverse, middle, center ### [Growth Models: A History](#9) ### [Working Tools](#27) ### [The Solow (Exogenous) Growth Model](#38) ### [Cross-Country Comparisons](#69) ### [Growth Accounting](#79) ### [Endogenous Growth](#96) ### [Digression: The Economics of Ideas](#103) ### [The Romer Model](#115) --- # Real Productivity .pull-left[ - The **only** way to increase income and standards of living (i.e. GDP per capita) is to increase .shout[real productivity], the amount of output produced per unit of input (i.e. per work-hour) ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/f5echyv5gt9iypy/productivity1.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # Measuring Productivity I .center[ ![:scale 60%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/bxm4mi02b2yydn6/blsproductivity.png?raw=1) [Bureau of Labor Statistics: Labor Productivity and Costs](https://www.bls.gov/lpc/) ] --- # Real Productivity Increases I .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/36xwyqu6n0uegt3/productivityovertime.png?raw=1) ] .source[Cox, Michael and Richard Alm, 1999, *Myths of Rich and Poor*, p. 43] --- # Real Productivity Increases II .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/2ckbeefhhgd1acq/caloriesovertime.png?raw=1) ] .footnote[ Biologically, a human needs approximately 2,500 calories a day to survive, with obvious variations based on height, weight, and sex.] .source[Source: [J. Bradford Delong](http://bradford-delong.com)] --- # Real Productivity Increases III .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/2hxtzy7zhxyr7d4/lightovertime.png?raw=1) ] .source[Nordhaus, William D, 1996, ["Do Real-Output and Real-Wage Measures Capture Reality?"](https://www.nber.org/chapters/c6064.pdf), *NBER Working Paper Series*] --- # What Causes Productivity (Differences)? .pull-left[ - Why isn't the whole world equally productive? - Different countries have different resources (factors of production) - Land, labor, capital, education, technology, etc. - Why not take machines and technology from wealthy countries and transfer them to poor countries? ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/c9l1458sy0vrrzz/technologytransfer.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # Growth Models: A History --- # Pre-Classical View: Mercantilism .left-column[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/pmumz9wb1p9fs9u/mun.png?raw=1) Thomas Mun (1571-1641) ] .right-column[ > "The ordinary means therefore to encrease our wealth and treasure is by Forraign Trade, wherein wee must ever observe this rule; to sell more to strangers yearly than wee consume of theirs in value. [sic]" ] .source[Mun, Thomas, 1664, *England's Treasure by Forraign Trade or the Ballance of our Forraign Trade is the Rule of our Treasure*] --- # Classical Economists on Growth I .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/w5ecx0628ihm9n2/smith.png?raw=1) Adam Smith 1723-1790 ] ] .right-column[ > "Nothing, hoever, can be more absurd than this whole doctrine of the balance of trade, upon which, not only these restraints, but almost all the other regulations of commerce are founded...But that trade which, without force or constraint, is naturally and regularly carried on between any two places is always advantageous, though not always equally so, to both," (Book IV, Chapter 3). > "Consumption is the sole end and purpose of all production; and the interest of the producer ought to be attended to only so far as it may be necessary for promoting that of the consumer," (Book IV, Chapter 9) ] .source[Smith, Adam, 1776, [*An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations*](https://www.econlib.org/library/Smith/smWN.html)] --- # Classical Economists on Growth II .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/2lfmrgfcrswf9s4/ricardo2.jpg?raw=1) David Ricardo 1772-1823 ] ] .right-column[ > "A nation is rich, not accordIng to the abundance of its money, nor to the high money value at which its commodities circulate, but according to the abundance of its commodities, contributing to its comforts and enjoyments." ] .source[Ricardo, David, 1815, [*Essay on the Influence of a Low Price of Corn on the Profits of Stock*](https://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&cad=rja&uact=8&ved=2ahUKEwjT0tP91OTkAhVmmuAKHbUQCgIQFjAAegQIABAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fla.utexas.edu%2Fusers%2Fhcleaver%2F368%2F368RicardoCornLawstable.pdf&usg=AOvVaw1SUmPWe09ERsqp2x-o-iMb)] --- # Classical Economists on Growth III .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/2lfmrgfcrswf9s4/ricardo2.jpg?raw=1) David Ricardo 1772-1823 ] ] .right-column[ > "After all the fertile land in the immediate neighbourhood of the first settlers were cultivated, if capital and population increased, more food would be required, and it could only be procured from land not so advantageously situated. Supposing then the land to be equally fertile, the necessity of employing more labourers, horses, &c. to carry the produce from the place where it was grown, to the place where it was to be consumed, although no alteration were to take place in the wages of labour, would make it necessary that more capital should be permanently employed to obtain the same produce." (Book IV, Chapter 9) > "Thus by bringing successively land of a worse quality, or less favourably situated into cultivation, rent would rise on the land previously cultivated, and precisely in the same degree would profits fall; and if the smallness of profits do not check accumulation, there are hardly any limits to the rise of rent, and the fall of profit," ] .source[Ricardo, David, 1815, [*Essay on the Influence of a Low Price of Corn on the Profits of Stock*](https://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&cad=rja&uact=8&ved=2ahUKEwjT0tP91OTkAhVmmuAKHbUQCgIQFjAAegQIABAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fla.utexas.edu%2Fusers%2Fhcleaver%2F368%2F368RicardoCornLawstable.pdf&usg=AOvVaw1SUmPWe09ERsqp2x-o-iMb)] --- # Classical Economists on Growth IV .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/2lfmrgfcrswf9s4/ricardo2.jpg?raw=1) David Ricardo 1772-1823 ] ] .right-column[ - **Law of Diminishing Returns**: adding more of one factor of production holding others constant will result in successively lower increases in output<sup>.red[1]</sup> - Conversely, to get more output, must use more of all factors! - **Marginal Product of Labor** `\((MP_L)=\frac{\Delta Y}{\Delta L}\)` will eventually decline, holding `\(\bar{K}, \bar{T}\)` - **Marginal Product of Capital** `\((MP_K)=\frac{\Delta Y}{\Delta K}\)` will eventually decline, holding `\(\bar{L}, \bar{T}\)` - **Marginal Product of Land** `\((MP_T)=\frac{\Delta Y}{\Delta T}\)` will eventually decline, holding `\(\bar{L}, \bar{K}\)` ] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> Note diminishing marginal returns (to one factor) is different from *decreasing returns to scale*, which is about a less than proportional increase in output from an increase in *all* factors.] --- # Classical Economists on Growth V .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/2lfmrgfcrswf9s4/ricardo2.jpg?raw=1) David Ricardo 1772-1823 ] ] .right-column[ - In Ricardo's view, *land* was a fixed factor - Start cultivation on most (agriculturally) productive land first - Extend cultivation into worse marginal land and worse marginal land... - As more land is used, more and more labor and capital would be needed to increase output (diminishing returns to land) ] --- # Classical Economists on Growth VI .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/2lfmrgfcrswf9s4/ricardo2.jpg?raw=1) David Ricardo 1772-1823 ] ] .right-column[ - Ultimately, marginal product of land would fall to 0 `\(\implies\)` economy in a permanent stationary state<sup>.red[1]</sup> - Profits to capital fall to 0 - Wages to laborers fall to subsistence level - Rents to land skyrocket due to land being the fixed factor<sup>2</sup> ] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> This pessimism is why people think economics was termed "the dismal science." Its real origin is even stranger, and darker... <sup>.red[2]</sup> This is the origin of the idea of a **Ricardian (economic) rent** - not merely a payment to landowners, but as in "rent-seeking."] --- # Classical Economists on Growth VII .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/d4yvuqhdegdfo5e/malthus.jpg?raw=1) Rev. Thomas Malthus 1766-1834 ] ] .right-column[ > "Population, when unchecked, increases in a geometrical ratio. Subsistence increases only in an arithmetical ratio. A slight acquaintance with numbers will shew the immensity of the first power in comparison of the second." > "The power of population is so superior to the power of the earth to produce subsistence for man, that premature death must in some shape or other visit the human race." ] .source[Malthus, Thomas, 1798, [*An Essay on the Principle of Population*](https://www.econlib.org/library/Malthus/malPop.html)] --- # Classical Economists on Growth VIII .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/d4yvuqhdegdfo5e/malthus.jpg?raw=1) Rev. Thomas Malthus 1766-1834 ] ] .right-column[ - .shout["Malthusian" Trap]: finite resources place a hard constraint on population growth - When societies grow too large, scarce resources kill off population (famine, disease, warfare) - Enormously important concept, we'll explore it in more detail in a later lesson ] .source[Malthus, Thomas, 1798, [*An Essay on the Principle of Population*](https://www.econlib.org/library/Malthus/malPop.html)] --- # Classical Economists on Growth IX .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/hptz0oijisiancz/marx.png?raw=1) Karl Marx (1818-1883) ] ] .right-column[ - Surplus value theory - Profit can only come from surplus value of labor extracted by capitalists - Capitalism will suffer from a "declining average rate of profit" - Concentration of capital, reserve army of the unemployed, business cycles - Marx's stages in the historical materialist dialectic - Proletariat will overthrow Bourgeoisie and usher in Socialism - Later (20<sup>th</sup> Century) Marxist historians: - Lenin: *Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism* - **Dependency Theory**: the Center (urban, developed countries) exploits the Periphery (rural, developing countries) - Developing countries can only develop by breaking free from the Center (West) ] --- # Rostow's Stages of Growth .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/wyoli85dp5mquu4/rostow.jpg?raw=1) Walt Whitman Rostow (1916-2003) ] ] .right-column[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-1-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .source[Rostow, W. W, 1960, *The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto*] --- # The Harrod-Domar Model I .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 49%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/r7uxmndxw4pky5i/harrod.jpg?raw=1) ![:scale 49%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/97bvdtm5akmmjup/domar.jpg?raw=1) **L**: Roy Harrod (1900-1978) **R**: Evsey Domar (1914-1997) ] ] .right-column[ - .shout[Harrod-Domar Model] of economic growth - Based off of Keynesian macroeconomic concepts: - **Marginal Propensity to Save (MPS)**, `\(\frac{\Delta S}{\Delta Y}\)`: proportion of (changes in) income saved `\(\in [0,1]\)` - **Incremental Capital-Output Ratio (ICOR)**, `\(\frac{\Delta K}{\Delta Y}\)`<sup>1</sup>: addition to capital stock `\(K\)` needed to produce an extra dollar of output `\(Y\)` - An economy's **equilibrium growth rate** `\(=\frac{MPS}{ICOR}\)` - `\(\uparrow K \implies \uparrow Y \implies \uparrow S\)` - We can impute the conditions necessary to yield a desired growth rate ] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> Or `\\(\frac{\Delta I}{\Delta Y}\\)`, where `\\(I\\)` is *net investment*, the change in capital stock.] --- # The Harrod-Domar Model II .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 49%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/r7uxmndxw4pky5i/harrod.jpg?raw=1) ![:scale 49%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/97bvdtm5akmmjup/domar.jpg?raw=1) **L**: Roy Harrod (1900-1978) **R**: Evsey Domar (1914-1997) ] ] .right-column[ - **"Knife's Edge equilibrium**: a single savings rate and ICOR that permits stable growth - Growth too low `\(\implies\)` depression - Growth too high `\(\implies\)` hyperinflation - Highly simplistic, yet extremely influential - Focus on unconsumed *surplus* to be used for investment - GDP growth rate `\(\propto\)` Investment share of GDP - Tendency to think "Development" `\(=\)` Growth `\(=\)` Industrialization - Ripe for Development planning from above ] --- # The Harrod-Domar Model III .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 49%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/r7uxmndxw4pky5i/harrod.jpg?raw=1) ![:scale 49%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/97bvdtm5akmmjup/domar.jpg?raw=1) **L**: Roy Harrod (1900-1978) **R**: Evsey Domar (1914-1997) ] ] .right-column[ - "**Financing gap"** between "required" investment rate (from model) and a country's actual saving rate - Low income countries can't increase savings `\(\implies\)` **foreign aid** from countries with higher savings will lead directly to rapid growth<sup>.red[1]</sup> ] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> Remember this argument!] --- # The Harrod-Domar Model IV .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/8rqega4jkxezbzm/easterly.png?raw=1) William Easterly 1957- ] ] .right-column[ > "To sum up, Domar's model was not intended as a growth model, made no sense as a growth model, and was repudiated as a growth model. So it was ironic that Domar's growth model became, and continues to be today, the most widely applied growth model in economic history," (p.28). ] .source[Easterly, William, 2010, *The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics* Cambridge: MIT Press] --- # Some Historical Context: 1930s-1960s .pull-left[ .polaroid[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/vo5u8seeglomiei/breadline.jpg?raw=1) ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ .polaroid[ ![:scale 65%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/tt4lb637k2v73c5/sovietindustrialization.jpg?raw=1) ] ] ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # Working Tools --- # An Aggregate Production Function I .pull-left[ - .shout[Aggregate production function]: rate at which an economy converts inputs into output<sup>.red[1]</sup> `$$Y=A*f(L,K,T)$$` - Economists often classify inputs into broad categories: <table> <thead> <tr> <th style="text-align:left;"> Factor </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> Owned By </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> Earns </th> </tr> </thead> <tbody> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> Land (T) </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> Landowners </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> Rent </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> Labor (L) </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> Laborers </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> Wages </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> Capital (K) </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> Capitalists </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> Interest </td> </tr> </tbody> </table> - "A" is called .onfire[total factor productivity], augments all factors to improve output - Often called "technology" but more like "ideas, incentives, and institutions" ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/cg5lbqrxsjij5iu/factors.jpg?raw=1) ] ] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> Technically this concept is borrowed from microeconomics, where it describes a firm's "technology."] --- # Theoretical Microfoundations I .pull-left[ - `\(N\)` firms `\((i=1,2,\cdots N)\)` all have the **same** production technology `$$y_i=a*f(L_i,K_i,T_i)$$` - All firms minimize cost of production and face the same factor prices:<sup>.red[1]</sup> - `\(p_L=w=MP_L\)` - `\(p_K=i=MP_K\)` - `\(p_T=r=MP_T\)` ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/f59prr1nm5u2cbx/corporation.jpg?raw=1) ] ] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> With the assumption of competitive markets, all factor prices (wages, interest, rents) are equal to the marginal productivity of labor, capital, and land, respectively.] --- # Theoretical Microfoundations II .pull-left[ - The economy behaves "as if" there is a single firm with technology `$$Y=A*f(L,K,T)$$` and facing factor prices, where aggregate inputs and output are: `$$\begin{align*} L&=l_1+l_2+ \cdots + l_N\\ K&=k_1+k_2+ \cdots + k_N\\ T&=t_1+t_2+ \cdots + t_N\\ Y&=y_1+y_2+ \cdots + y_N\\ \end{align*}$$` ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/f59prr1nm5u2cbx/corporation.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # An Aggregate Production Function: Implications Under constant returns: - If two countries have the same technology, there is no economic advantage to size - Labor productivity `\(\left(\frac{Y}{L}\right)\)`, output-per-worker/hour, is determined only by `\(\left(\frac{K}{L}\right)\)`, capital-per-worker/hour `$$Y = MP_LL + MP_KK + MP_T T$$` - With competitive markets, firms pay each factor its marginal product, firms earn no profits<sup>.red[1]</sup> .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> This is also called the "product exhaustion theorem," and comes from [Euler's Theorem for homogeneous functions](https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Homogeneous_function#Positive_homogeneity) (constant returns functions are homogeneous of degree 1).] --- # An Aggregate Production Function: Cobb-Douglas I .pull-left[ - A very common functional form in economics is .shout[Cobb-Douglas] `$$Y=AK^{\alpha}L^{1-\alpha}$$` - Exponents `\((\alpha)\)` and `\((1-\alpha)\)` are "output-elasticities" - A 1% increase in K (L) will yield a `\(\alpha\)`% `\((1-\alpha)%\)` increase in Y - Constant returns to scale<sup>.red[1]</sup>: a k% increase in *all* factors of production will yield a k% increase in `\(Y\)` - [More about Cobb-Douglas functions](http://microf19.classes.ryansafner.com/class/05-class) ] .pull-right[ `$$Y = K^{0.5}L^{0.5}$$`
] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> Only when all exponents sum to 1. In technical terms, the production function is "homogeneous of degree 1"] --- # An Aggregate Production Function: Cobb-Douglas I .pull-left[ `$$Y=AK^{\alpha}L^{1-\alpha}$$` - GDP `\((Y)\)`: "Total Output" `\(=\)` "Total Income" for all factor-owners - Exponents `\(\alpha\)` and `\((1-\alpha)\)` are the **Factor Shares** of National Income - `\(\alpha\)`: capital's share of national income - `\((1-\alpha)\)`: labor's share of national income - Empirically, very stable: - Capital's share: `\(\alpha \approx 0.3\)` - Labor's share: `\(1-\alpha \approx 0.7\)` ] .pull-right[ `$$Y = K^{0.3}L^{0.7}$$`
] --- # Aggregate Production Function: Labor I .pull-left[ - Look at Labor, holding other factors constant:<sup>.red[1]</sup> .content-box-green[ .green[**Example**]: When `\\(\bar{K}=9\\)` ] `$$Y=3L^{0.5}$$` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-6-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> We often consider "the short run" where `\\(K\\)` is fixed, and production functions are simply functions of labor with fixed capital `\\(y=f(\bar{k},l)\\)`.] --- # Aggregate Production Function: Labor II .pull-left[ - Look at Labor, holding other factors constant: - The .shout[marginal product of labor]: the additional output produced by an additional unit of labor (holding other factors constant) `$$MP_L=\frac{\Delta Y}{\Delta L}$$` - The .shout[average product of labor]: output per worker `$$AP_L=\frac{Y}{L}$$` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-8-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Aggregate Production Function: Capital I .pull-left[ - Look at Capital, holding other factors constant: .content-box-green[ .green[**Example**]: When `\\(\bar{L}=9\\)` ] `$$Y=3K^{0.5}$$` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-10-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Aggregate Production Function: Capital II .pull-left[ - The .shout[marginal product of capital]: the additional output produced by an additional unit of capital (holding other factors constant) `$$MP_K=\frac{\Delta Y}{\Delta K}$$` - The .shout[average product of capital]: output per unit of capital `$$AP_K=\frac{Y}{K}$$` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-12-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> This is `\\(\frac{\partial Y}{\partial K}\\)`.] --- # Capital and Labor .pull-left[ - Often compare **capital-to-labor ratio** `\(\left(\frac{K}{L} \right)\)` - .shout[Capital "widening"]: stock of capital increases, but capital per worker `\(\left(\frac{K}{L}\right)\)` does not change - Increase in `\(K\)` is same rate as increase in labor and depreciation - .shout[Capital "deepening"]: stock of capital per worker `\(\left(\frac{K}{L}\right)\)` is increasing ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/smweawkts91mtut/gmworkers.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # The Solow Model (Exogenous Growth) --- # Kaldor's Stylized Facts About Growth .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/0mvst288krqlu7w/kaldor.jpg?raw=1) Nicholas Kaldor (1908-1986) ] ] .right-column[ > "A satisfactory model concerning the nature of the growth process in a capitalist economy must also account for the remarkable historical constancies revealed by recent empirical investigations." (p.591) 1. Output per worker grows over time 2. Capital per worker grows over time 3. The capital-to-output ratio is approximately constant over time 4. Capital and labor's share of output is approximately constant over time 5. The return to capital is approximately constant over time 6. Levels of output per person vary widely across countries ] .source[Kaldor, Nicholas, 1957, "A Model of Economic Growth," *Economic Journal* 67(268): 591-624] --- # The Solow (Neoclassical) Growth Model .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/lbaq4sn3omma38k/solow.jpg?raw=1) Robert Solow (1924-) Economics Nobel 1987 ] ] .right-column[ > "All theory depends on assumptions which are not quite true. That is what makes it theory. The art of successful theorizing is to make the inevitable simplifying assumptions in such a way that the final results are not very sensitive," (p.65) > "The characteristic and powerful conclusion of the Harrod-Domar line of thought is that even for the long run the economic system is at best balanced on a knife-edge of equilibrium growth...The bulk of [Solow's] paper is devoted to a model of long-run growth which accepts all of the Harrod-Domar assumptions [but] instead I suppose that [output] is produced by labor and capital under the **standard neoclassical conditions**," (pp.65-66) ] .source[Solow, Robert, 1956, "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth," *Quarterly Journal of Economics* 70(1): 65-94] --- # The "Simple" Solow Model: Key Assumptions - An aggregate Cobb-Douglas production function - Diminishing `\(MP_K\)` - Can accumulate physical capital `\((K)\)` - Technology grows **exogenously** - Constant rate of Savings and of Investment `\((s)\)` - I am going to leave out excess parts of the model: role of taxes, interest rates, etc, on consumption, saving, and investment<sup>.red[1]</sup> .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> This isn't a macroeconomics course!] --- # The "Simple" Solow Model: Equations - `\(C_t+I_t=Y_t=f(K,L)\)` - Income is equal to consumption plus investment - Output is equal to the production function - Income = Output -- - `\(I_t=sf(K_t,L_t)\)` - Investment is equal to the fraction of income (output) saved `\(s\)` times output -- - `\(K_{t+1}=K_t (1-\delta) + I_t\)` - The stock of capital `\(K\)` changes over time from depreciation `\((\delta)\)` and new investment `\(I_t\)` -- - `\(L_t=L\)` - The stock of labor is constant over time --- # The "Simple" Solow Model: Implications - `\(K_{t+1}=K_t(1-\delta)+sf(K_t,L_t)\)` - Plugging equation 2 into equation 3 -- - Steady-State equilibrium: `\(\delta K = sf(K,L)\)` - Amount of capital depreciation is the same as the amount saved & invested --- # Equations and Implications, in Terms of `\(k\)` - Restate model in terms of `\(k \equiv \frac{K}{L}\)`, i.e. divide everything by `\(L\)` to get "per worker" - `\(y = \frac{Y}{L}\)`, output per worker - `\(k = \frac{K}{L}\)`, capital per worker -- 1. `\(c_t+i_t=y_t=f(k_t)\)` 2. `\(i_t=sf(k_t)\)` 3. `\(k_{t+1}=k_t(1-\delta)+i_t\)` -- - Implications 1. `\(k_{t+1}=k_t(1-\delta)+sf(k_t)\)` 2. Steady-State equilibrium: `\(\delta k = sf(k)\)` --- # The "Simple" Model Graphically: Capital and Depreciation I .pull-left[ - Whenever .green[Investment] `\(>\)` .red[Depreciation]: - Capital stock is **growing** over time, `\(g_K > 0\)` - Adding more *new* capital than is *lost* to depreciation - Movement to the right on graph `\(k \rightarrow\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-13-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The "Simple" Model Graphically: Capital and Depreciation II .pull-left[ - Whenever .green[Investment] `\(<\)` .red[Depreciation]: - Capital stock is **shrinking** over time, `\(g_K < 0\)` - Adding less *new* capital than is *lost* to depreciation - Movement to the left on graph `\(\leftarrow k\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-14-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The "Simple" Model Graphically: Capital & the Steady State .pull-left[ - Whenever .green[Investment] `\(=\)` .red[Depreciation] - Capital stock reaches a **steady state**, `\(g_K = 0\)` - Adding exactly as much *new* capital that is *lost* to depreciation - No movement on graph - .green[**Steady State level** of capital]: `\(k_t^*: sf(k_t)=\delta k_t, \, g_k=0\)` - .blue[**Steady State level** of output] - Amount available for consumption, `\(c_t^*=y_t^*-i_t^*\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-15-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # Comparative Statics: A Change in Savings I .pull-left[ - What if consumers decide to **save more**? - `\(s_1=0.30\)` - `\(s_2=0.50\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-16-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # Comparative Statics: A Change in Savings II .pull-left[ - What if consumers decide to **save more**? - `\(s_1=0.30\)` - `\(s_2=0.50\)` - Investment `\(i_t\)` increases - Steady state level of capital `\(k_t^*\)` increases - Steady state output increases `\(y_t^*\)` - Steady state amount of consumption - Decreases at first from more savings - Increases from more output produced ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-17-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # Comparative Statics: A Change in Depreciation I .pull-left[ - What if depreciation costs increase? - `\(\delta_1=0.02\)` - `\(\delta_2=0.04\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-18-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # Comparative Statics: A Change in Depreciation II .pull-left[ - What if depreciation costs increase? - `\(\delta_1=0.02\)` - `\(\delta_2=0.04\)` - Investment `\(i_t\)` decreases - Steady state level of capital `\(k_t^*\)` decreases - Steady state output decreases `\(y_t^*\)` - Steady state amount of consumption `\(c_t^*\)` decreases ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-19-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The Golden Rule Level of k I .pull-left[ - Different values of `\(s\)` lead to different steady state levels of `\(k^*\)`, which is *best*? - The best steady state is one where there is the highest possible consumption per person `$$c^*=(1-s)f(k^*)$$` - Increase in `\(s\)` - Reduces consumption's share of income `\((1-s)\)` - Results in higher `\(k^*\)` and higher `\(y^*\)` - Find the value of `\(s\)` (and `\(k^*)\)` that *maximize* `\(c^*\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-20-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The Golden Rule Level of k II .pull-left[ `$$\max_{c^*} c^* = \underbrace{f(k^*)}_{y^*} - \underbrace{\delta k^*}_{=i^* \text{ in SS}}$$` `$$\begin{align*} \frac{d \, c^*}{d \, k^*} &= \frac{d \, f(k^*)}{d \, k^*} - \frac{d \, \delta k^*}{d \, k^*}\\ 0 & = MP_K - \delta \\ MP_K & = \delta \\ \end{align*}$$` - **Golden Rule level of** `\(\mathbf{k^*_{GR}}\)` where slope of depreciation line `\(=\)` slope of production function, `\(f(k^*)\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-21-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The Golden Rule Level of k III .pull-left[ - **Golden Rule level of** `\(\mathbf{k^*_{GR}}\)` where slope of depreciation line `\(=\)` slope of production function, `\(f(k^*)\)` - **Golden Rule level of** `\(s_{GR} = \frac{\delta k^*_{GR}}{y^*_{GR}}\)` - In this example, `\(s_{GR}=\frac{0.02(625)}{25}=0.50\)` - Optimal level of savings is 0.50 or 50%! ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-22-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The Golden Rule Level of k IV .pull-left[ - Policy implications: policymakers can choose `\(s\)` to `\(\max c_i^*\)` at `\(k^*_{GR}\)` - Change taxes or government spending ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-23-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # Main Properties of the Solow Model .pull-left[ 1. There exists a unique steady state capital to labor ratio, `\(k^*\)` - Where investment = depreciation - `\(sf(k)=\delta(k)\)` 2. Higher savings rate `\(s\)` implies a higher steady state value of `\(k^*\)` 3. An economy **converges** over time to the steady state level of `\(k^*\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-24-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The "Simple" Solow Model and Kaldor's Facts 1. In steady state, `\(g_y=0\)` and `\(g_k=0\)`: output and capital (per worker) do now grow! 2. The only explanation that fits with Kaldor's facts (1-2) is that all countries must be BELOW their steady states 3. Growth would have to be slowing down over time - These are motivations for the "full Solow" model --- # The "Full" Solow Model I .pull-left[ - Add two new "laws of motion" beyond just capital: - **Population** grows at constant rate `\(n\)` over time - `\(L_{t+1}=L_t(1+n)\)` - `\(g_L = n\)` - **Technology** grows at constant rate `\(g\)` over time - `\(A_{t+1}=A_t(1+g)\)` - `\(g_A = g\)` `\((g\)` is the growth rate of technology) - Redefine `\(k \equiv \frac{K_t}{A_tL_t}\)` as capital per *effective* worker - Labor is being augmented by technology, hence `\(A_t \times L_t\)` - `\(A_{t+1}L_{t+1} = A_tL_t(1+n)(1+g)\)` ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ab87jtj63ls8hy8/popgrowth.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # The "Full" Solow Model II - Long story short, our new takeaway implications: 1. `\(\Delta k = sf(k_t)-(\delta+n+g)k_t\)` - Capital per effective worker is equal to investment (first term) minus **break-even investment** 2. Break even investment: `\((\delta+n+g)k\)` - Amount of investment necessary to keep `\(k\)` constant, consists of: - `\(\delta k\)`: to replace capital depreciation - `\(nk\)`: to provide capital to new workers - `\(gk\)`: to provide capital for new "effective workers" created by technology --- # The "Full" Solow Model: Graphically I .pull-left[ - Whenever .green[Investment] `\(=\)` .red[Break-even Investment] - Capital stock reaches a **steady state**, `\(g_K = 0\)` - Adding exactly as much *new* capital that is *needed* to break-even - No movement on graph - .green[**Steady State level** of capital]: `\(k_t^*: sf(k_t)=(\delta+n+g)k_t, \, g_k=0\)` - .blue[**Steady State level** of output] - Amount available for consumption, `\(c_t^*=y_t^*-i_t^*\)` ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-25-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The "Full" Solow Model: Graphically II .pull-left[ - Growth rates in the *steady state*: | Variable | Symbol | Growth Rate | |----------|--------|-------------| | Capital per effective worker | `\(k=\frac{K}{AL}\)` | 0 | | Output per effective worker | `\(y=\frac{Y}{AL}\)` | 0 | | Output per worker | `\(\frac{Y}{L}=Ay\)` | `\(g\)` | | TFP | `\(A\)` | `\(g\)` | | Labor (population) | `\(L\)` | `\(n\)` | | Total Capital | `\(K=ALk\)` | `\(n+g\)` | | Total Output | `\(Y = yAL\)` | `\(n+g\)` | - Interesting: growth rate of output per worker grows *solely* from rate of TFP progress `\((g)\)`! ] .pull-right[ <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-26-1.png" width="504" /> ] --- # The "Full" Solow Model and Kaldor's Facts 1. Output per worker grows at rate `\(g\)` (Kaldor's Fact 1) 2. Capital per worker grows at rate `\(g\)` (Kaldor's Fact 2) 3. Capital and output grow at the same rate over time (Kaldor's Fact 3) 4. Capital and labor's share of output `\((\alpha\)` and `\(1-\alpha\)`, respectively) do not change over time (Kaldor's Fact 4) 5. The return to capital is constant (it can be shown to be `\(r=\alpha(k^*)^{\alpha-1}\)`) - What about Kaldor's Fact 6: levels of output per worker vary widely across countries? --- class: inverse, center, middle # Cross-Country Comparisons --- # Solow Model Cross-Country Comparisons: Convergence .pull-left[ - All else equal, poor countries (low `\(\frac{Y}{L}\)` and `\(\frac{K}{L})\)` should grow faster than rich ones (high `\(\frac{Y}{L}\)` and `\(\frac{K}{L})\)` - Income gap between wealthy and poor countries should cause living standards to .shout[converge] over time ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/5atmnkr35zz8ph2/convergence.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Convergence: Technical - Near the balanced growth path `\(k \rightarrow (k^*)\)` at a speed proportional to its distance from `\(k^*\)`: `$$k(t) \approx k^* + e^{-[1-\alpha k^*](n+g+\delta) t}(k_0-k^*)$$` - In other words - **the further away from (closer to) `\(k^*\)` your country is, the faster (slower) you should grow** --- # Convergence? I <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-27-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Convergence? II .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/pvtjurdg8vjy6mc/jamesbessen.jpg?raw=1) James Bessen 1958- ] ] .right-column[ > "By the early twentieth century, British textile equipment manufacturers were shipping power looms and other textile equipment around the globe. Mills in India, China, and elsewhere not only used the same equipment as British mills, but they were often run by experienced British managers aided by British master weavers and spinners and engineers. Nevertheless, their output per worker was far less than that of the English or American mills because their workers -- using the exact same machines -- lacked the same knowledge and skills. Western weavers were 6.5 times more productive. The English and American cotton textile industries held a sustained economic advantage for decades, despite paying much higher wages," (pp.18-19). ] .source[Bessen, James, 2015, *Learning by Doing: The Real Connection between Innovation, Wages, and Wealth*, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press] --- # Convergence? III .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/pvtjurdg8vjy6mc/jamesbessen.jpg?raw=1) James Bessen 1958- ] ] .right-column[ > "[T]he technical knowledge needed to install, manage, and operate this technology, along with the necessary institutiosn and organizations to allow large numbers of workers to acquire this knowledge, did not appear in these countries for many decades. Cotton textile workers in China, India, and Japan in 1910 had the same machines as those in England, but their productivity was far less than that of the English or American workers because they lacked the same knowledge and skills. Even when English managers ran mills in India and China, productivity tended to be low because the English managers had to adapt their knowledge to a different environment and culture.," (p.98). ] .source[Bessen, James, 2015, *Learning by Doing: The Real Connection between Innovation, Wages, and Wealth*, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press] --- # Convergence? IV .pull-left[ - All else is not equal! - Solow model predicts .shout[conditional convergence]: countries converge to their *own* steady states determined by saving, population growth, and education `\((s, n, g)\)` - *IF* countries had similar institutions, then they should converge ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ggqgre7j2eg3c09/growthpuzzle.png?raw=1) [From MR University](https://mru.org/courses/principles-economics-macroeconomics/solow-model-economic-growth) ] ] --- # Conditional Convergence <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-28-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> .source[Pritchett, Lant, 1997, "Divergence, Big Time," *Journal of Economic Perspectives* 11(3): 3-17] --- # Divergence, Big Time .pull-left[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/4v9asothgw81s6z/divergencebigtime.png?raw=1) ] ] .pull-right[ > "[F]rom 1870 to 1990 the ratio of per capita incomes between the richest and the poorest countries increased by roughly a factor of five and that the difference in income between the richest country and all others has increased by an order of magnitude." ] .source[Pritchett, Lant, 1997, "Divergence, Big Time," *Journal of Economic Perspectives* 11(3): 3-17] --- # *Convergence*, Big Time? .pull-left[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/9wjo8t8dnpbame2/convergencebigtime.png?raw=1) ] ] .pull-right[ > "While unconditional convergence was singularly absent in the past, there has been unconditional convergence, beginning (weakly) around 1990 and emphatically for the last two decades." ] .source[Johnson, Paul and Chris Papageorgiou, 2018, "What Remains of Cross-Country Convergence?" *Journal of Economic Literature*, forthcoming] --- # Convergence .pull-left[ - Consider two types of economic growth - .blue["Cutting-edge Growth"] - tends to be much slower - has to push out the PPF with *new* innovation and progress - .red["Catching-up Growth"] - tends to be much faster - can *mimic* and import *existing* innovation from other countries ] .pull-right[ ![](05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-29-1.png)<!-- --> ] --- # Growth on the Frontier is Hard I .pull-left[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/d6z5b94c86xozbg/sciencedmr.png?raw=1) Source: [The Atlantic (Nov 16, 2018)](https://www.theatlantic.com/science/archive/2018/11/diminishing-returns-science/575665/) ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/7aed5qqdxgncgc6/runningoutofideas.png?raw=1) Source: [Freakonomics (Nov 29, 2017)](http://freakonomics.com/podcast/no-new-ideas/) ] ] --- # Growth on the Frontier is Hard II .pull-left[ .center[ ![:scale 60%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/6j0vtfi1syalcbz/gordonriseandfall.png?raw=1) ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 70%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/u2igo8d8ixi5p6s/greatstagnation.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- class: inverse, center, middle # Growth Accounting --- # The Solow Model: Growth Accounting I `$$g_Y=\frac{F_A A}{Y}*g_A+ \alpha g_K+(1-\alpha)g_L$$` - Output growth `\(g_Y\)` can be explained as the growth of "technology" `\(g_A\)` and the growth of factors `\((\alpha g_K + (1-\alpha)g_L)\)`<sup>.red[1]</sup> -- - Used to determine how much of total output can be explained by growth in factors and "everything else," known as the .shout[Solow Residual] - often interpreted as "technology" -- - We can directly measure (roughly) `\(Y, L, K\)` and `\(\alpha\)`, but not `\(\frac{F_A A}{Y}\)`, the Solow residual - Measure it as `\(\text{Solow Residual}=g_Y- \alpha g_K-(1-\alpha)g_L\)` .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> All `\\(g\\)`'s stand for growth rates, or percentage change, of the relevant variable `\\((Y, A, K, L)\\)`. See the [class notes page](/class/05-class) for a derivation of Growth Accounting based on Solow (1957)] .source[Solow, Robert, 1957, "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function," *The Review of Economics and Statistics* 39(3): 312-320] --- # The Solow Model: Growth Accounting II .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 65%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/lbaq4sn3omma38k/solow.jpg?raw=1) Robert Solow (1924-) Economics Nobel 1987 ] ] .right-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/yylo45vj2jrhxfx/solowcalculations.png?raw=1) ] ] .source[Solow, Robert, 1957, "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function," *The Review of Economics and Statistics* 39(3): 312-320] --- # The Solow Model: Growth Accounting III .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/lbaq4sn3omma38k/solow.jpg?raw=1) Robert Solow (1924-) Economics Nobel 1987 ] ] .right-column[ Solow's findings for 1909-1949 in the United States: 1. Output per worker grew by about 100% 2. Capital-to-labor ratio grew by about 30% ("capital-deepening") 3. Technology grew by about 87.5% - i.e. 87.5% of the growth in output per worker came from Technology; 12.5% from increases in capital per worker 4. Measure of Technology fell in a number of recession/depression years and rose during expansions -- technology is "pro-cyclical" 5. Aggregate production function displays a positive and diminishing marginal product of capital ] .source[Solow, Robert, 1957, "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function," *The Review of Economics and Statistics* 39(3): 312-320] --- # The Solow Model: Growth Accounting IV <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-31-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Growth Accounting: TFP <img src="05-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-32-1.png" width="504" /> --- # Exogenous Growth, With Human Capital I .pull-left[ - Solow model(s) can't account for all differences between countries (based on `\(\frac{K}{L}\)` ratio) - What about if we add .shout[*human* capital] - skills and education embodied in people, such that it augments labor productivity? ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ioqj00n8fb87xe3/mind.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # Exogenous Growth, With Human Capital II .pull-left[ `$$Y_t=K_t^\alpha \left(A_tH_t\right)^{1-\alpha}$$` - Replacing `\(L\)` with `\(AH\)` - `\(A\)` again grows at (exogenous) rate `\(g_A=g\)` - `\(H_t = L_tG(E)\)` - Labor `\(L_t\)` is affected by `\(G(E)\)`, where `\(E\)` is .shout[education] - `\(G(E)\)` is the function that describes how education affects labor `\(L_t\)` - How to model `\(G(E)\)`? ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ioqj00n8fb87xe3/mind.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # Exogenous Growth, With Human Capital II .pull-left[ `$$Y_t=K_t^\alpha \left(A_tH_t\right)^{1-\alpha}$$` - How to model `\(G(E)\)`? - Presumably positive (more education `\(\implies\)` more human capital) - Diminishing returns? Signalling theory of education? ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ioqj00n8fb87xe3/mind.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # Exogenous Growth, With Human Capital III .pull-left[ `$$Y_t=K_t^\alpha \left(A_tH_t\right)^{1-\alpha}$$` - The dynamics of this model are virtually identical to Solow's - Good: easy to solve - Bad: we fail to explain `\(g\)` (still exogenously assumed) ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ioqj00n8fb87xe3/mind.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # Exogenous Growth, With Human Capital IV .pull-left[ "In 1988 output per worker in the United States was more than 35 times higher than output per worker in Niger. In just over ten days the average worker in the United States produced as much as an average worker in Niger produced in an entire year." "Differences among countries can be attributed to differences in human capital, physical capital, and productivity...**Different capital intensities** in the two countries **contributed a factor of 1.5** to the income differences, while **different levels of educational attainment contributed a factor of 3.1**. The **remaining difference - a factor of 7.7 remains as the productivity residual**, (p.83). ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/hq1aglwa3aabtbt/halljones.png?raw=1) ] ] .source[Hall, Robert E, and Charles I Jones, 1999, "Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others?" *Quarterly Journal of Economics* 114(1): 83-116] --- # Exogenous Growth, With Human Capital V .pull-left[ "Our hypothesis is that differences in capital accumulation, productivity, and therefore output per worker are **fundamentally related to differences in social infrastructure across countries**. By social infrastructure we mean the **institutions and government policies that determine the economic environment** within which individuals accumulate skills, and firms accumulate capital and produce output," (p. 84). ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 60%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/4qc8quxymhsfqcy/socialinf.png?raw=1) ] ] .source[Hall, Robert E, and Charles I Jones, 1999, "Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others?" *Quarterly Journal of Economics* 114(1): 83-116] --- class: inverse, center, middle # Endogenous Growth --- # The Romer Model I .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/zj5nl5b7y5036ja/paulromer.jpg?raw=1) Paul Romer (1955-) Economics Nobel 2018 ] ] .right-column[ > "**Growth in this model is driven by technological change** that arises **from intentional investment decisions made by profit-maximizing agents**. The distinguishing feature of the **technology** as an input is that it is neither a conventional good nor a public good; it **is a non-rival, partially excludable good.** Because of the nonconvexity introduced by a nonrival good, **price-taking competition cannot be supported.** Instead, the **equilibrium is one with monopolistic competition.** > "The main conclusions are that the **stock of human capital determines the rate of growth,** that** too little human capital is devoted to research in equilibrium**, that **integration into world markets will increase growth rates**, and that **having a large population is not sufficient to generate growth,**" (pp.S71). - Paper cited [28,747 times](https://scholar.google.com/scholar?q=endogenous+technological+change&hl=en&as_sdt=0&as_vis=1&oi=scholart) ] .source[Romer, Paul M, 1990, "Endogenous Technological Change," *Journal of Political EConomy* 98(5-2): S71-S102] --- # Aside: Paul Romer .pull-left[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/b48ee2xym3m8wr9/romerburningman.png?raw=1) Source: [New York Times: Sept 5, 2019](https://www.nytimes.com/2019/09/05/upshot/paul-romer-burning-man-nobel-economist.html) ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/69zy566ehnfwo3w/romerworldbank.png?raw=1) Source: [Financial Times: Jan 25, 2018](https://www.ft.com/content/be72f8e2-0144-11e8-9650-9c0ad2d7c5b5) ] ] --- # The Romer Model II .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/zj5nl5b7y5036ja/paulromer.jpg?raw=1) Paul Romer (1955-) Economics Nobel 2018 ] ] .right-column[ - We'll explore the *features* of Romer's model, equations and graphs are far too complicated<sup>.red[1]</sup> - Romer's model builds on 30 years of macro models since Solow (1956): .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> But otherwise, his first 8 pages are quite easy and enjoyable to read!] ] --- # Macro Models In the 30 Years Since Solow (1956) - **Ramsey-Kass-Koopmans model** (1965): Solow model with .onfire[microfoundations]! - Savings rate `\(s\)` is endogenized: - "infinitely-lived" utility-maximizing individuals decide to supply labor and rent capital to cost-minimizing firms in order to earn income, which they can consume and save for future periods - single steady state equilibrium - groundwork for all modern macro dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models -- - **Overlapping Generations (Diamond) model** (1965): - Individuals live for 2 periods only (work and retire), determine the savings rate - Multiple steady state equilibria possible - Economy subject to dynamic inefficiency --- # The Motivations for Romer - Problems with how Solow models the aggregate economy: 1. "Knowledge" (TFP) has a non-rival component to it 2. Markets/aggregate production function cannot possibly be competitive and constant returns to scale - Market power/monopolistic competition - Increasing returns to scale 3. Knowledge does not grow exogenously, but is the result of market forces and optimizing choices: people and firms face incentives to create and exploit it (or not) --- class: inverse, center, middle # Digression: The Economics of Ideas --- # The Economic *Problem* with Ideas I .pull-left[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/32yfwsk7g4sfvvr/privatesign.png?raw=1) ] ] -- .pull-right[ <table class="table" style="width: auto !important; margin-left: auto; margin-right: auto;"> <thead> <tr> <th style="text-align:left;"> </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> Rivalrous </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> Nonrival </th> </tr> </thead> <tbody> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;font-weight: bold;font-weight: bold;vertical-align: middle !important;" rowspan="2"> Excludable </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> PRIVATE GOODS </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> COMMON RESOURCES </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> (Houses, Jeans) </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> (Fisheries, Environment) </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;font-weight: bold;font-weight: bold;vertical-align: middle !important;" rowspan="2"> Nonexcludable </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> CLUB GOODS </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> PUBLIC GOODS </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> (Wifi, Cable TV) </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> (Asteroid Defense) </td> </tr> </tbody> </table> ] --- # The Economic *Problem* with Ideas II .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/wyifyyvs8xbyijc/jefferson1.jpg?raw=1) Thomas Jefferson (1743-1826) ] ] .right-column[ > "He who receives an idea from me, receives instruction himself without lessening mine; as he who lights his taper at mine, receives light without darkening me. That ideas should freely spread from one to another over the globe, for the moral and mutual instruction of man, and improvement of his condition, seems to have been peculiarly and benevolently designed by nature, when she made them, like fire, expansible over all space, without lessening their density in any point, and like the air in which we breathe, move, and have our physical being, incapable of confinement or exclusive appropriation." ] .source[Jefferson, Thomas, 13 Aug 1813, "Letter to Isaac MacPherson," ] --- # The Economic *Problem* with Ideas II .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/8xrpsdf2mj2z4fj/macaulay.png?raw=1) Thomas Macaulay (1800-1859) ] ] .right-column[ > "It is then on men whose profession is literature, and whose private means are not ample, that you must rely for a supply of valuable books. Such men must be remunerated for their literary labour...It is desirable that we should have a supply of good books; we cannot have such a supply unless men of letters are liberally remunerated, and the least objectionable way of remunerating them is by means of copyright...The system of copyright has great advantages, and great disadvantages...Copyright is monopoly, and produces all the effects which the general voice of mankind attributes to monopoly...Monopoly is an evil...For the sake of the good we must submit to the evil; but the evil ought not to last a day longer than is necessary for the purpose of securing the good..." ] .source[Macaulay, Thomas, 1841 Parliamentay speech against Serjeant Talfourd's 1841 Copyright Bill] --- # High Fixed Costs, Low Marginal Costs I .pull-left[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/j5rxriut8sinvob/pharmaceutical.png?raw=1) ] ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/4ibyb8oohmmge5z/genericpill.jpg?raw=1) ] ] - It costs about $1,000,000,000 and 10 years on average to create a new drug. Once discovered, it costs the firm (or it's competitors!) about $0.50/pill to manufacture. --- # High Fixed Costs, Low Marginal Costs II .pull-left[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/5kfldu00lodqa1s/got1.png?raw=1) ] ] -- .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/lt9c30lpwho7uh8/gotpirated.png?raw=1) Source: [Washington Post (Sept 8, 2017)](https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/morning-mix/wp/2017/09/08/game-of-thrones-was-pirated-more-than-a-billion-times-far-more-than-it-was-watched-legally/) ] ] --- # Positive Spillovers .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 70%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/10htmt0dupcb3kb/nordhaus.jpg?raw=1) William Nordhaus (1941-) Economics Nobel 2018 ] ] .right-column[ > "We conclude that [about 2.2%] of the social returns from technological advances over the 1948-2001 period was captured by producers, indicating that most of the benefits of technological change are passed on to consumers rather than captured by producers," (p.1) ] .source[Nordhaus, William, 2004, ["Schumpeterian Profits in the American Economy: Theory and Measurement,"](https://www.nber.org/papers/w10433) *NBER Working Paper* 10433] --- # Property Rights in Innovation .pull-left[ - For these economic reasons, .shout[patent] (for ideas and inventions) and .shout[copyright] (for expressions) laws exist - Grant *temporary* monopoly to holder in order to recover their fixed costs and provide incentive to undertake (risky and expensive) research/creativity - A utilitarian *tradeoff* between incentives and access ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 60%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/cihnj15juyus7wj/patent.png?raw=1) ![:scale 60%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/l4vep529mbzckfh/copyright.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # This Implies Market Power .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/zj5nl5b7y5036ja/paulromer.jpg?raw=1) Paul Romer (1955-) Economics Nobel 2018 ] ] .right-column[ > "If all inputs were paid their value marginal product, the firm would suffer losses," (p.S76). > "There is little doubt that much of the value to society of any given innovation or discovery is not captured by the inventor, and any model that missed these spillovers would miss important elements of the growth process. Yet it is still the case that private, profit-maximizing agents make investments in the creation of new knowledge and that they earn a return on these investments by charging a price for the resulting goods that is greater than the marginal cost of producing the goods," (p.S90). ] .source[Romer, Paul M, 1990, "Endogenous Technological Change," *Journal of Political EConomy* 98(5-2): S71-S102] --- # Are Intellectual Property Rights in the Model? .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/zj5nl5b7y5036ja/paulromer.jpg?raw=1) Paul Romer (1955-) Economics Nobel 2018 ] ] .right-column[ > "Although other assumptions about secrecy and property rights could be considered, the equilibrium here is based on the assumption that anyone engaged in research has free access to the entire stock of knowledge. This is feasible because knowledge is a nonrival input. All researchers can take advantage of `\(A\)` at the same time," (p.S83). ] .source[Romer, Paul M, 1990, "Endogenous Technological Change," *Journal of Political EConomy* 98(5-2): S71-S102] --- class: inverse, center, middle # The Romer Model --- # Romer Model: Assumptions I .pull-left[ - Population (or labor supply) and the total stock of human capital in the population are fixed `\((\bar{L}, \bar{H})\)` - Four factors of production: 1. Labor `\(L\)` 2. Physical capital `\(K\)` - a stock of "machines" that can be accumulated - diminishing returns 3. Human capital `\(H\)` - rivalrous, embodied in `\(L\)` and `\(K\)` 4. Technology `\(A\)` - nonrival, exists beyond individuals, grow indefinitely - a stock, like `\(K\)`, that can be accumulated - no restrictions on returns! - measured as countable "new designs" for capital ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/cg5lbqrxsjij5iu/factors.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Romer Model: Assumptions II - The economy has three sectors: 1. **Research sector** - Uses inputs `\(H\)` and the existing stock of knowledge `\(A_{t-1}\)` to produce new knowledge, `\(A_t\)` - Measured in "new designs" for capital `\(K\)` -- 2. **Intermediate goods sector** - Takes inputs `\(H\)` and `\(A_t\)` to produce `\(K\)` for use in final goods sector -- 3. **Final goods sector** - uses `\(L\)`, `\(H\)`, and `\(K\)` to produce final output `\(Y\)` -- - Output can be consumed, or saved (to be used to make new capital, `\(K)\)`: `$$Y_t=C_t+S_t$$` - Fixed supply of human capital is allocated to research sector or manufacturing based on relative manufacturing wages and return to new designs `$$\bar{H}=H_A+H_Y$$` --- # The Nature of "Knowledge" I .pull-left[ - Knowledge `\((A)\)` is a stock that can be accumulated, like physical capital `\((K)\)` - To produce new knowledge, you need to use the existing stock of knowledge - i.e. need the idea of gravity to get relativity, we need both to get quantum mechanics, etc. ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ioqj00n8fb87xe3/mind.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # The Nature of "Knowledge" II .pull-left[ > "[A] college-educated engineer working today and one working 100 years ago have the same human capital, which is measured in terms of years of forgone participation in the labor market. The engineer working today is more productive because he or she can take advantage of all of the additional knowledge accumulated as design problems were solved during the last 100 years," (pp. S83-S84). ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ioqj00n8fb87xe3/mind.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # The Nature of "Knowledge" III .pull-left[ `$$\Delta A = \delta H_A A$$` - `\(\delta\)`: a productivity parameter - `\(H_A\)`: fraction of human capital available `\((\bar{H})\)` allocated to research - Knowledge need not exhibit constant returns to scale - Would doubling human capital and doubling the existing stock of knowledge lead to *twice* the new knowledge produced? ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ioqj00n8fb87xe3/mind.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # The Nature of "Knowledge" IV .pull-left[ - Takeaways from knowledge: 1. Devoting more human capital to research `\((H_A)\)` leads to more knowledge `\(\Delta A\)` 2. The larger the total stock of knowledge `\((A)\)`, the higher the productivity of labor in the research sector ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ioqj00n8fb87xe3/mind.png?raw=1) ] ] --- # The Model's Equilibrium .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 75%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/zj5nl5b7y5036ja/paulromer.jpg?raw=1) Paul Romer (1955-) Economics Nobel 2018 ] ] .right-column[ - In the model's equilibrium (p.S88): 1. Consumers decide between `\(C\)` and `\(S\)` based on interest rate `\(r\)` 2. Holders of `\(H\)` decide whether to work in Research sector `\((H_A)\)` or in Manufacturing `\((H_Y)\)` based on existing stock of knowledge `\(A\)`, price of designs, and wages in manufacturing 3. Final goods producers choose cost-minimizing inputs of `\(L\)`, `\(H\)`, and `\(K\)` 4. Each firm owning `\(A\)` (designs) sets prices to maximize profit given interest rate and market demand curves in final product market 5. Potential entrants to market consider price of designs in entry decision 6. Supply equals demand for each good ] .source[Romer, Paul M, 1990, "Endogenous Technological Change," *Journal of Political EConomy* 98(5-2): S71-S102] --- # Romer Model: Growth Rate - As in full Solow model, growth rate of output per worker `\(\frac{Y}{L}\)` is the growth rate of knowledge `\((A)\)`, i.e. `\(g\)` - Main problem with Solow (exogenous) growth model(s): `\(g\)` is assumed as a constant number - Romer *endogenizes* `\(g\)`, sp how does it grow? -- `$$g=\frac{\delta H - \Lambda \rho}{\sigma \Lambda + 1}$$` - `\(\Lambda = \frac{\alpha}{(1-\alpha-\beta)(\alpha+\beta)}\)`<sup>.red[1]</sup> - `\(\delta\)`: a productivity parameter (of `\(H)\)` - `\(\rho\)`: discount rate (from Ramsey-Kass-Koopmans model) - `\(\sigma\)`: growth rate of utility (from Ramsey-Kass-Koopmans model) .footnote[<sup>.red[1]</sup> `\\(\alpha\\)` and `\\(\beta\\)` are exponents from Cobb-Douglas production function: `\\(Y=H^\alpha L^\beta K^{1-\alpha-\beta}\\)`] --- # Romer Model Implication I - R&D Is Critical - Economies tend to undersupply human capital to research: > The most obvious reason is that research has positive external effects. An additional design raises the productivity of all future individuals who do research, but because this benefit is nonexcludable, it is not reflected at all in the market price for designs. The second and an equally important reason...is that research produces an input that is purchased by a sector that engages in monopoly pricing. The markup of price over marginal cost forces a wedge between the marginal social product of an input used in this sector and its market compensation," (p.S96) -- - Policy implications: > "Within the confines of the model, the social optimum can be achieved by subsidizing the accumulation of A," (p.S97) > "A subsidy to physical capital accumulation may be a very poor substitute for direct subsidies that increase the incentive to undertake research. In the absence of feasible policies that can remove the divergence between the social and private returns to research, a second-best policy would be to subsidize the accumulation of total human capital," (p.S99) --- # Romer Model Implication II - Trade Liberalization - A large population is *not* sufficient for greater technology (and thus, economic growth), it requires access to a *larger market* (division of labor)! > If access to a large number of workers or consumers were all that mattered, having a large population would be a good substitute for trade with other nations. The model here suggests that what is important for growth is integration not into an economy with a large number of people but rather into one with a large amount of human capital, (p.S98) > "The most interesting positive implication of the model is that an economy with a larger total stock of human capital will experience faster growth. This finding suggests that free international trade can act to speed up growth. It also suggests a way to understand what it is about developed economies in the twentieth century that permitted rates of growth of income per capita that are unprecedented in human history. The model also suggests that low levels of human capital may help explain why growth is not observed in underdeveloped economies that are closed and why a less developed economy with a very large population can still benefit from economic integration with the rest of the world," (p.S99) --- # One Test of the Model: "Market Access" Literature - Sokoloff (1988): counties in the U.S. in the 19<sup>th</sup> century that had access to navigable waterways had higher rates of patenting (proxy for innovation, adding to `\(A)\)` than those that did not - Even clearer: counties that *gained* access to new waterway (i.e. a new canal) saw sharp increase in patenting! .source[Sokoloff, Kenneth L, 1988, ["Inventive Activity in Early Industrial America: Evidence From Patent Records, 1790-1846,"]() *NBER Working Paper* 2707] --- # Takeaways from Growth Models .pull-left[ 1. HICs have more output per worker and capital per worker than LICs ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/i1c37p6ue7pvtl2/economicgrowth.jpeg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Takeaways from Growth Models .pull-left[ 1. HICs have more output per worker and capital per worker than LICs 2. The accumulation of physical capital itself explains a very small part of differences in income ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/i1c37p6ue7pvtl2/economicgrowth.jpeg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Takeaways from Growth Models .pull-left[ 1. HICs have more output per worker and capital per worker than LICs 2. The accumulation of physical capital itself explains a very small part of differences in income 3. "Knowledge" or "TFP" explains the overhelming part of growth differences across the world ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/i1c37p6ue7pvtl2/economicgrowth.jpeg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Takeaways from Growth Models .pull-left[ 1. HICs have more output per worker and capital per worker than LICs 2. The accumulation of physical capital itself explains a very small part of differences in income 3. "Knowledge" or "TFP" explains the overhelming part of growth differences across the world 4. Solow model predicts LICs should grow at faster rates than HICs ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/i1c37p6ue7pvtl2/economicgrowth.jpeg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Takeaways from Growth Models .pull-left[ 1. HICs have more output per worker and capital per worker than LICs 2. The accumulation of physical capital itself explains a very small part of differences in income 3. "Knowledge" or "TFP" explains the overhelming part of growth differences across the world 4. Solow model predicts LICs should grow at faster rates than HICs 5. The evidence for (4) is mixed and controversial ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/i1c37p6ue7pvtl2/economicgrowth.jpeg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Takeaways from Growth Models .pull-left[ 1. HICs have more output per worker and capital per worker than LICs 2. The accumulation of physical capital itself explains a very small part of differences in income 3. "Knowledge" or "TFP" explains the overhelming part of growth differences across the world 4. Solow model predicts LICs should grow at faster rates than HICs 5. The evidence for (4) is mixed and controversial 6. Growth literature suggests economies can grow faster by subsidizing the accumulation of capital, or human capital, or "knowledge" - The evidence that we are able to do this, or have been able to, is *quite poor* ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/i1c37p6ue7pvtl2/economicgrowth.jpeg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Takeaways from Growth Models .pull-left[ 1. HICs have more output per worker and capital per worker than LICs 2. The accumulation of physical capital itself explains a very small part of differences in income 3. "Knowledge" or "TFP" explains the overhelming part of growth differences across the world 4. Solow model predicts LICs should grow at faster rates than HICs 5. The evidence for (4) is mixed and controversial 6. Growth literature suggests economies can grow faster by subsidizing the accumulation of capital, or human capital, or "knowledge" - The evidence that we are able to do this, or have been able to, is *quite poor* 7. An economy's "TFP" is more sensitive to its institutions and incentives than simply amassing `\(K\)` or `\(H\)` or `\(A\)` ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/i1c37p6ue7pvtl2/economicgrowth.jpeg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Takeaways from Growth Models II .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/ggqgre7j2eg3c09/growthpuzzle.png?raw=1) ] --- # Growth Models: An Appraisal .pull-left[ - For all of their flaws, growth models are part of the "shared" language of development experts, policy makers, and macroeconomists - Explain (some) mechanisms of growth that we can model and predict (some) consequence of (some) policy changes - Give us a measure of how much we *can* explain based on what we understand, and how much we *cannot* explain and *need* to understand > All models are wrong. Some are useful. - George Box ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![:scale 100%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/i1c37p6ue7pvtl2/economicgrowth.jpeg?raw=1) ] ]